Vladimir Ilyich Lenin

NOTEBOOK “α”

(“ALPHA”)


LIEFMANN, CARTELS AND TRUSTS

Professor Dr. R. Liefmann, Cartels and Trusts and the Further Development of Economic Organisation, 2nd edition, Stuttgart, 1910. Library of Jurisprudence and Political Science.

 A popular book giving a good
outline of the subject matter. The
standpoint is that of a dull-witted,
smug, complacent bourgeois
apologist.

The facts are not badly selected but, of course, apologetically.

N.B.: p. 161:

 “In Germany there have been a very large
number of mergers that are not (???) of a monop-
olistic nature.... A typical example—not to cite
numerous instances from a more remote period—
is the gunpowder industry. Already in the seven-
ties, 19 gunpowder factories merged in a single
joint-stock company. In 1890, this merged
with its most powerful rival to form the Verei-
nigte Köln-Rottweiler Pulverfabriken. This big
joint-stock company then formed cartels not
only with other gunpowder factories, but also
with the dynamite trust mentioned above.
Thus there was formed quite a modern amal-
gamation of all the German explosives factories,
which, together with the similarly organised
French and American explosives factories, have
of the divided the whole world among themselves, so
to speak” (p. 161).[1]
division
of the
world

The number of industrial cartels in Germany (1905) was 3 8 5 (in reality more: p. 25).[2]

N.B. |||| Riesser (p. 137), in quoting these statistics, adds: “about 12,000 firms participated ‘directly’ in these cartels”. Riesser, The German Big Banks and Their Concentration, 3rd edition, Jena, 1910.


The number of international cartels (with German participation) is about 100 (p. 30: in 1897 it was about 40).[3]

Potassium Industry
First cartel 1879:  4 firms
Prices rise 1898: 10 firms
“Potassium fever”: 1901— 21 firms
1909— 52
(“Some collapsed”)

The Steel Trust in America (1908: 165,211 workers) 1907—210,180 workers (total wages—$161 million), net profit—$170 million, capital—$1,100 million (p. 124).

In 1908, the biggest firm in the German mining industry, Gelsenkirchner Bergwerksgesellschaft, had 1,705 employees + 44,343 workers (wages—70.5 million marks).

(p. 135). In 1902 (June 17, 1902) Schwab founded the Shipbuilding Company, capital $70.9 million—of which Schwab had $20 million. Later this company went bankrupt; the public were robbed!


(173, etc.) “Interlocking”, “holdings” (passim), “abolishing isolation” (p. 155)—these are Liefmann’s “catch-words” for avoiding (and obscuring) Marx’s concept of “socialisation”.[4]

((End of extracts from Liefmann))


Notes

[1] Ibid., p. 252.—Ed.

[2] Ibid., p. 202.—Ed.

[3] See present edition, Vol. 22, p. 62.—Ed.

[4] Marx’s concept of “socialisation”, based on a scientific analysis of the objective laws of development of capitalist society, points to the necessity and inevitability of the means of production passing from private capitalist ownership to social ownership. Lenin showed that the conflict between the production relations and the productive forces under capitalism becomes very acute in the era of imperialism. In this last stage of capitalism the concentration and socialisation of production reach the highest level (see present edition, Vol. 22, pp. 205, 207, 302-03). This makes it easier, after the victory of the socialist revolution, for the workers’ and peasants’ state to take over the basic means of production and organise planned production in the interests of the people. p. 56

  STILLICH, MONEY AND BANKING | FROM PRINCIPLES OF SOCIAL ECONOMICS  

< Backward     Document Index     Forward >
Works Index   |   Volume 39 | Collected Works   |   L.I.A. Index